Stigler was born in Seattle, Washington, the son of hungarian Elsie Elizabeth[1](Hungler, born in Bakonypéterd) and bavarian Joseph Stigler.[2] He was of German and Hungarian descent[3][4] and spoke German in his childhood.[5] He graduated from the University of Washington in 1931 with a B.A. and then spent a year at Northwestern University, from which he obtained his MBA in 1932. It was during his studies at Northwestern that Stigler developed an interest in economics and decided on an academic career.[6]
After he received a tuition scholarship from the University of Chicago, Stigler enrolled there in 1933 to study economics and went on to earn his PhD in economics in 1938.
At Chicago, he was greatly influenced by Frank Knight, his dissertation supervisor. Milton Friedman, a friend for over 50 years,[7] commented that it was remarkable for Stigler to have passed his dissertation under Knight, as only three or four students had ever managed to do so in Knight's 28 years at Chicago. Stigler's influences included Jacob Viner and Henry Simons as well as students W. Allen Wallis and Friedman.
Stigler is best known for developing the Economic Theory of Regulation (1971), also known as regulatory capture, which says that interest groups and other political participants will use the regulatory and coercive powers of government to shape laws and regulations in a way that is beneficial to them. This theory is a component of the public choice field of economics but is also deeply opposed by public choice scholars belonging to the "Virginia School," such as Charles Rowley.[8] He also carried out extensive research in the history of economic thought.
Stigler's most important contribution to economics was published in his landmark 1961 article, "The Economics of Information."[9] According to Friedman, Stigler "essentially created a new area of study for economists." Stigler stressed the importance of information: "One should hardly have to tell academicians that information is a valuable resource: knowledge is power. And yet it occupies a slum dwelling in the town of economics."[6]
His 1962 article "Information in the Labor Market" developed the theory of search unemployment.[10]
He was known for his sharp sense of humor, and he wrote a number of spoof essays. In his book The Intellectual and the Marketplace, for instance, he proposed Stigler's Law of Demand and Supply Elasticities: "all demand curves are inelastic and all supply curves are inelastic too." The essay referenced studies that found many goods and services to be inelastic over the long run and offered a supposed theoretical proof; he ended by announcing that his next essay would demonstrate that the price system does not exist.
Another essay, "A Sketch on the Truth in Teaching," described the consequences of a (fictional) set of court decisions that held universities legally responsible for the consequences of teaching errors.[12] The Stigler diet is also named after him.[13]
Stigler wrote numerous articles on the history of economics, published in the leading journals and republished 14 of them in 1965. The American Economic Review said, "many of these essays have become such well-known landmarks that no scholar in this field should be unfamiliar with them... The lucid prose, penetrating logic, and wry humor... have become the author's trademarks."[14][15] However, Deirdre McCloskey has criticised his characterisation of Adam Smith as a father of the 'greed is good' school of economics as a poor reading of the Scottish philosopher's views.[16]
His relative Antal Koppány[22][23] was famous for playing draw against Bobby Fischer who was himself of hungarian ancestry through his biological father Paul Neményi.
Bibliography
edit
(1939). "Production and Distribution in the Long Run," Journal of Political Economy, 47(3), pp. 305–327 (arrow-scrollable).
([1941] 1994). Production and Distribution Theories: The Formative Period. New York: Macmillan. & Description arrow-scrollable preview.
(1942) The Theory of Competitive Price. The Macmillan Company.[24]
(1945). "The Cost of Subsistence," Journal of Farm Economics, 2, pp. 303–314. Arrow-scrollable.
(1961). "The Economics of Information," Journal of Political Economy, 69(3), pp. 213–225.
(1962a). "Information in the Labor Market." Journal of Political Economy, 70(5), Part 2, pp. 94–105.
(1962b). The Intellectual and the Marketplace. Selected Papers, no. 3. Chicago: University of Chicago Graduate School of Business. Reprinted in Sigler (1986), pp. 79–88
(1962c). (With Claire Friedland) "What Can Regulators Regulate," Journal of Law and Economics, pp. 3–21.
(1962d). "The problem of the Negro," "New Guard" 101(5), pp. 11–12.
(1963). (With Paul Samuelson) "A Dialogue on the Proper Economic Role of the State." Selected Papers, no. 7. pp. 3–20. Chicago: University of Chicago Graduate School of Business
(1963). Capital and Rates of Return in Manufacturing Industries. National Bureau of Economic Research, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press
(1965). Essays in the History of Economics. University of Chicago Press. 1965.[25]
(1968). The Organization of Industry. Description & arrow-scrollable preview. Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin
(1970). (With J.K. Kindahl) The Behavior of Industrial Prices. National Bureau of Economic Research, New York: Columbia University Press
(1971). "The Theory of Economic Regulation." Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, no. 3, pp. 3–18 (arrow-scrollable).
(1972). "The Adoption of Marginal Utility Theory," History of Political Economy, 4(2), pp. 571–586. Also below at * (1982b).
(1975). Citizen and the State: Essays on Regulation
(1982a). "The Process and Progress of Economics," Nobel Memorial Lecture, 8 December (with bibliography)
(1982b). The Economist as Preacher, and Other Essays. Chicago: University of Chicago Press
(1983). The Organization of Industry
(1985). Memoirs of an Unregulated Economist. University of Chicago Press. 2003. ISBN 978-0-226-77440-4. autobiography
(1986). The Essence of Stigler, K.R. Leube and T.G. Moore, ed. Arrow-scroll to respective essays. ISBN 0-8179-8462-3
For comprehensiveness, see Vicky M. Longawa (1993), "George J. Stigler: A Bibliography," Journal of Political Economy, 101(5), pp. 849–862. Arrow–scrollable.
(2002). Zingales, L. et al. (Eds.), George Stigler 50 Years Later. Stigler Center.
^National Academy of Sciences; Office of the Home Secretary (1 May 1999). Biographical Memoirs. National Academies Press. pp. 342–. ISBN 978-0-309-06434-7.
^Zsolt, Gyurina (2022-09-24). "Nobel-díjas rokonnal büszkélkedhet a bakonypéterdi Hofstadter Mátyás" [Mátyás Hofstadter from Bakonypéterd can boast a Nobel Prize-winning relative]. KISALFOLD (in Hungarian). Retrieved 2024-09-13.
^"The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 1982". Archived from the original on 2019-12-17. Retrieved 2023-02-05.
^Sowell, Thomas (1996), Migrations and Cultures: A World View, New York: Basic Books, p. 82, ISBN 978-0465045891, ...it may be indicative of how long German cultural ties endured [in the United States] that the German language was spoken in childhood by such disparate twentieth-century American figures as famed writer H. L. Mencken, baseball stars Babe Ruth and Lou Gehrig, and by the Nobel Prize-winning economist George Stigler.
^ abMilton Friedman (1992). "George Joseph Stigler January 17, 1911 – December 1, 1991," Archived February 9, 2005, at the Wayback MachineBiographical Memoirs. National Academy of Sciences.
^George Stigler: A Personal Reminiscence, Hoover, https://www.jstor.org/stable/2138591 Archived 2021-12-23 at the Wayback Machine
^Palda, Filip. A Better Kind of Violence: The Chicago School of Political Economy, Public Choice, and the Quest for and Ultimate Theory of Power. Cooper-Wolfling Press. 2016.
^George J. Stigler (1961). "The Economics of Information," Journal of Political Economy, 69(3), pp. 213–325. Archived 2010-06-21 at the Wayback Machine
^George J. Stigler (1962). "Information in the Labor Market." Journal of Political Economy, 70(5), Part 2, pp. 94–105. Archived 2022-02-21 at the Wayback Machine
^View/Search Fellows of the ASA Archived 2016-06-16 at the Wayback Machine, accessed 2016-07-23.
^George J. Stigler, 1973. "A Sketch of the History of Truth in Teaching," Journal of Political Economy, 81(2, Part 1), pp. 491 Archived 2024-03-01 at the Wayback Machine–495.
^Based on his 1945 article. "The Cost of Subsistence," Journal of Farm Economics, 2, pp. 303–314. Arrow-scrollable. Archived 2022-02-04 at the Wayback Machine
^Thomas Sowell, review in American Economic Review (June, 1965), p. 552.
^George J. Stigler, Essays in the History of Economics (University of Chicago Press, 1965).
^McCloskey, Deirdre Nansen, Preface, Mullen, Roger, Smith, Craig, & Mochrie, Robbie (eds.) *2023), Adam Smith: The Kirkcaldy Papers, Adam Smith Global Foundation, Kirkcaldy, pp. 7 & 8, ISBN 9781399963497.
^"The Rise, Decline, and Reemergence of Classical Liberalism | Belmont University | Nashville, TN". www.belmont.edu. Archived from the original on 2021-05-26. Retrieved 2021-05-26.
^"Stigler, George J. (1911–1991)". www.libertarianism.org. Archived from the original on 2021-06-12. Retrieved 2021-06-27.
^"APS Member History". search.amphilsoc.org. Archived from the original on 2023-01-20. Retrieved 2023-01-20.
^"George Joseph Stigler". American Academy of Arts & Sciences. Archived from the original on 2023-01-20. Retrieved 2023-01-20.
^"George J. Stigler". www.nasonline.org. Archived from the original on 2019-05-05. Retrieved 2023-01-20.
^Tóni bácsi, aki Katziáner Antalként született, majd nevét magyarosította Koppányra, végül ő is Amerikába került. Ő arról híres, hogy döntetlent játszott a világhírű sakkozóval, Bobby Fischerrel.
^Lachmann, L. M. (1943). "Review of The Theory of Competitive Price". Economica. 10 (39): 264–265. doi:10.2307/2549996. ISSN 0013-0427.
^Reviewed at Shepard B. Clough (1965). "Essays in the History of Economics. George J. Stigler," The Journal of Modern History, 37(3), p. 357.[permanent dead link] & Herbert M. Bernstein (1967), "Essays in the History of Economics by George J. Stigler," Technology and Culture, 8(1), pp. 136–138. Archived 2024-03-01 at the Wayback Machine
References
edit
Diamond, Arthur M., Jr. (2005). "Measurement, Incentives, and Constraints in Stigler's Economics of Science." The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 12, no. 4637–63.
Friedman, Milton (1993). "George Stigler: A Personal Reminiscence," Journal of Political Economy 101(5), arrow-scrollable pp. 768–773.
Friedman, M. (1999). "George J. Stigler, 1911–1991. National Academies Press. A Biographical Memoir.
Hammond, J. Daniel, and Claire H. Hammond, ed. (2006). Making Chicago Price Theory: Friedman–Stigler Correspondence, 1945–1957. Routledge. 165 pp. ISBN 0-415-70078-7.
Palda, Filip (2016). A Better Kind of Violence: Chicago Political Economy, Public Choice, and the Quest for an Ultimate Theory of Power. Cooper-Wolfling Publishers. ISBN 978-0-9877880-7-8.
Steelman, Aaron (2008). "Stigler, George J. (1911–1991)". In Hamowy, Ronald (ed.). Stigler, George J. (1911–1991). The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism. Thousand Oaks, California: Sage; Cato Institute. pp. 492–493. doi:10.4135/9781412965811.n299. ISBN 978-1412965804. LCCN 2008009151. OCLC 750831024.
"Stigler, George Joseph" by Peter Newman, v. 4, p. 498.
"Stigler as an historian of economic thought" by Thomas Sowell, v. 4, pp. 498–499.
"Stigler's contribution to microeconomics and industrial organization," by Richard Schmalense, v. 4, pp. 499–500
Schmalensee, Richard (1983). "George Stigler's Contributions to Economics, The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 85(1), pp. 77–86 (arrow-scroll searchable).
External links
edit
Wikiquote has quotations related to George Stigler.