Stephen Marglin

Summary

Stephen Alan Marglin is an American economist. He is the Walter S. Barker Professor of Economics at Harvard University, a fellow of the Econometric Society, and a founding member of the World Economics Association.[1]

Stephen A. Marglin
Born
California, United States
NationalityAmerican
Academic career
InstitutionHarvard
Alma materHarvard
InfluencesKarl Marx
John Maynard Keynes
Friedrich Hayek
Websitehttps://scholar.harvard.edu/marglin

Background edit

Marglin grew up in a moderately left-wing[2] Jewish family and attended Hollywood High School in Los Angeles[3] before moving to Harvard for his university studies in 1955.[4] He earned membership into Phi Beta Kappa,[2] and graduated summa cum laude (1959).[4] He was subsequently honored with a Harvard Junior Fellowship (1960–63),[5] and was later a Guggenheim fellow.[6]

Career edit

Marglin started out as a neoclassical economist, and was regarded, even while still an undergraduate, as the star of Harvard's economics department.[4] Arthur Maass, the Frank G. Thomson Professor of Government, Emeritus, at Harvard,[7] once remembered how Marglin, "when he was just a senior, wrote two of the best chapters in a book published by a team of graduate students and professors."[4] His exceptional early contributions to neoclassical theory[4] led to his becoming a tenured professor at Harvard in 1968, one of the youngest in the history of the university.[2]

Since the late 1960s, Marglin, following the lead of people such as Samuel Bowles, Herbert Gintis, and Arthur MacEwan, rejected orthodox economics and began expressing dissenting views in his academic work.[3][4][8] According to his former teacher, James Duesenberry, Marglin's career subsequently "suffered" because of his department and the university authorities in general taking a negative view of this change.[4] Economist Brad DeLong noted in a similar vein that the wider community of "Ivy League economists" took a rather dim view of Marglin's post-tenure "deviancy", something that has "not been pretty" to observe.[9]

Marglin has published in areas including the foundations of cost–benefit analysis, the workings of the labor-surplus economy, the organization of production, the relationship between the growth of income and its distribution, and the process of macroeconomic adjustment.[10]

He wrote the widely discussed[11] 1971-1974 paper "What do bosses do?", first published in France by his friend André Gorz,[12] followed by a series of others,[13] in which he argued that

the most important innovation of the Industrial Revolution was not technological, but organizational: the linear hierarchy (master–journeyman–apprentice) typical of crafts in the premodern era was replaced by the pyramidal hierarchy (boss–foreman–worker) of the modern, capitalist enterprise. How did this happen? What hold did the capitalist have on the worker that permitted this new form of organization to thrive and eventually to dominate?

The conventional answer is superior efficiency, a better mousetrap. If the capitalist enterprise comes into existence because of its superior efficiency, then the boss can entice the worker by offering him more money than the worker could earn on his own. [...] By contrast, the answer in "Bosses" is that the capitalist organization of work came into existence not because of superior efficiency but in consequence of the rent-seeking activities of the capitalist.[14]

Elsewhere, Marglin argued: "The obstacles to liberating the workplace lie not only in the dominance of classes in whose interest it is to perpetuate the authoritarian workplace, but also in the dominance of the knowledge system that legitimizes the authority of the boss. In this perspective, to liberate the workplace it is hardly sufficient to overthrow capitalism. The commissar turned out to be an even more formidable obstacle to workers' control than the capitalist."[15]

His highly cited and influential work "What do bosses do?" came as part of Marglin's disagreement with fellow Harvard professor David Landes over aspects of the Industrial Revolution;[16] years later, Landes wrote "What do bosses really do?" in reply.[17]

Marglin is critical of those who explicitly set out to deny the normative aspect of economics—something that he believes "really started with the British economist Lionel Robbins"[18]—arguing that opposing ideology is "a methodological error [...] What is ideology, after all, but the unproved assumptions, beliefs, and values that must underlie any intellectual inquiry, or for that matter, any form of contemplation or action? [...] As long as we deny the ideological component of our theories, we shall never transcend it."[19]

Marglin's 21st-century research has included analysis of the foundational assumptions of economics, concentrating on whether they represent universal human values or merely "reflect western culture and history." The Dismal Science (2008) looks at, amongst other things, the manner in which community is steadily gutted as human relations are replaced with market transactions.[20]

Marglin's most recent book is Raising Keynes: A Twenty-First-Century General Theory (2021). The book rescues the central insight of John Maynard Keynes' great work, The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, that capitalism left to its own devices has no mechanism for guaranteeing full employment, and that consequently the government must provide a visible hand to work in tandem with the invisible hand of the market. "Rescues" because the mainstream view today is unchanged from the 1930s when Keynes wrote the General Theory: namely, that the problem is imperfections that impede the working of markets, warts on the body of capitalism rather than the body itself. Over the years the radical, heterodox Keynes was transformed by the mainstream into a super-sophisticated theorist of warts, specifically, a theorist of how capitalism can get stuck if wages are insufficiently flexible. The wart theory allowed economists to accept some of Keynes's policy insights, in particular the limitations of monetary policy and the necessity for countercyclical fiscal policy in extremis, while rejecting the idea that there is any more serious flaw than the warts themselves. And, supremely important, restricting the role of government to alleviating the warts is a strictly short-term, limited endeavor.

Raising Keynes shows how and why the orthodox reading of Keynes is wrong and substantiates Keynes's insight that, even if you strip capitalism of its warts, you still have a system that has no mechanism for reliably producing enough jobs. The state is needed not on an occasional, intermittent basis, but continually, in the long run as well as in emergencies.

In line with his view of economics teaching as "extremely narrow and restrictive," for some years Marglin offered an alternative to Greg Mankiw's course in introductory economics.[21][22][23][24]

Partial publications list edit

Books edit

  • Raising Keynes: A Twenty-First-Century General Theory. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. 2021.
  • The Dismal Science: How Thinking Like an Economist Undermines Community. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. 2008.
  • Decolonizing Knowledge: From Development to Dialogue. Oxford: Clarendon Press. 1996. (Co-editor with Frédérique Apffel-Marglin).
  • Dominating Knowledge: Development, Culture, and Resistance. Oxford: Clarendon Press. 1990b. (Co-editor with Apffel-Marglin).
  • The Golden Age of Capitalism: Reinterpreting the Postwar Experience. Oxford: Clarendon Press. 1990a. (Co-editor with Juliet Schor).
  • Growth, Distribution, and Prices. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. 1984a. ISBN 9780674364158.
  • Value and Price in the Labour-Surplus Economy. Oxford: Clarendon Press. 1976. ISBN 978-0-19-828194-8.

Articles, papers, and chapters edit

  • "La Science Economique: Une Science Lugubre?" (PDF). In Jean-Pierre Potier, ed., Les Marmites De L'histoire: Melanges En L'honneur De Pierre Dockes, pp. 25–38. Paris: Classiques Garnier. 2014.
  • Marglin, Stephen A. (2013). "Premises for a New Economy". Development. 56 (2): 149–154. doi:10.1057/dev.2013.20. S2CID 84461684.
  • "Where Did All the Money Go? Stimulus in Fact and Fantasy" (PDF). INET Research Note #031. 2013. Archived from the original (PDF) on 2013-11-13. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help) (With Peter M. Spiegler).
  • "We Have to Wake up and Smell the Flowers". European Journal of Economics and Economic Policies: Intervention. 8 (2): 237–245. 2011. doi:10.4337/ejeep.2011.02.01. hdl:10419/277217.
  • Pattanaik, Prasanta K.; Cullenberg, Stephen, eds. (2004), "Individualism and Scarcity", Globalization, culture, and the limits of the market: essays in economics and philosophy, Themes in Economics, New Delhi New York: Oxford University Press, ISBN 978-0-195-66446-1
  • "Development as Poison: Rethinking the Western Model of Modernity" (PDF). Harvard International Review. 25 (1): 70–75. 2003.[permanent dead link]
  • Economic Myths. Séminaire Hétérodoxies du Matisse. Pantheon-Sorbonne University. 2002.
  • Marglin, Stephen A. (2000). "Keynes Without Nominal Rigidities". Harvard Institute of Economic Research Paper No. 1907. doi:10.2139/ssrn.250790. S2CID 152307514. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  • "Understanding Capitalism: Control vs. Efficiency". In B. Gustaffsson, ed., Power and Economic Institutions: Reinterpretations in Economic History. Aldershot: Edward Elgar. 1991.
  • Bhaduri, Amit; Marglin, Stephen (1990). "Unemployment and the real wage: the economic basis for contesting political ideologies" (PDF). Cambridge Journal of Economics. 14 (4): 375–393. doi:10.1093/oxfordjournals.cje.a035141. (With Amit Bhaduri).
  • Marglin, Stephen A. (1990). "Sustainable Development: A Systems of Knowledge Approach". The Black Scholar. 21 (1): 35–42. doi:10.1080/00064246.1990.11412956. JSTOR 41067671.
  • "Knowledge and Power". In F. Stephen, ed., Firms, Organization and Labour. London: Macmillan. 1984b.
  • "Catching Flies with Honey: An Inquiry into Management Initiatives to Humanize Work". Economic Analysis and Workers' Management. 13 (4): 473–487. 1979.
  • Marglin, Stephen A. (1975). "What Do Bosses Do? Part II". Review of Radical Political Economics. 7 (1): 20–37. doi:10.1177/048661347500700102. S2CID 153539367.
  • Marglin, Stephen A. (1974). "What Do Bosses Do?". Review of Radical Political Economics. 6 (2): 60–112. doi:10.1177/048661347400600206. S2CID 153641564.
  • "Origines et fonction de la parcellisation des tâches. À quoi servent les patrons?", in André Gorz (ed.), Critique de la division du travail, Paris, Seuil, 1973, p. 41-89.
  • Marglin, Stephen A. (1970). "Investment and Interest: A Reformulation and Extension of Keynesian Theory". The Economic Journal. 80 (320): 910–931. doi:10.2307/2229905. JSTOR 2229905.
  • Marglin, Stephen A. (1963). "The Opportunity Costs of Public Investment". Quarterly Journal of Economics. 77 (2): 274–289. doi:10.2307/1884403. hdl:10.2307/1884403. JSTOR 1884403.
  • Marglin, Stephen A. (1963). "The Social Rate of Discount and The Optimal Rate of Investment". Quarterly Journal of Economics. 77 (1): 95–111. doi:10.2307/1879374. JSTOR 1879374.

Political and other views edit

A liberal in his earlier years, since the mid-1960s Marglin has been a Leftist,[3] and has even been labelled a Marxist,[2] though he describes himself as Marxist "only in the sense of not being anti-Marx."[4] He identifies as a cultural Jew and a secular humanist, and maintains his practice of Judaism for the sense of community it provides.[25]

Marglin was arrested in 1972 while demonstrating against the Vietnam War.[2] He supported the Occupy movement,[26] and contributed to a teach-in at Occupy Harvard.[27]

Personal life edit

Marglin is married to Christine Marglin (née Benvenuto). She is the author of Shiksa: The Gentile Woman in the Jewish World and Sex Changes: A Memoir of Marriage, Gender, and Moving On. Marglin's previous two marriages, to Carol Kurson (died 2020) and Frederique Apffel-Marglin, ended in divorce. From youngest to oldest, his children (including stepchildren) are Nasia Benvenuto-Ladin, 2021 high-school grad; Yael Benvenuto-Ladin, rising college senior; Gabriel Benvenuto-Ladin, working in theater production; Jessica Marglin, associate professor of Jewish Studies and religion, law, and history; Elizabeth Marglin, freelance writer; David Marglin, attorney; and Marc Weisskopf, professor of environmental epidemiology and physiology.

Notes edit

  1. ^ "Marglin's Curriculum Vitae" (PDF). Retrieved 30 August 2015.
  2. ^ a b c d e Groll, Elias J. (1 June 2009). "Radical Harvard economics professor defies 'established order' of the 1950s". The Harvard Crimson. Retrieved 29 October 2012.
  3. ^ a b c Lee, Tom (12 May 1975). "The Radicalization of Stephen Marglin". The Harvard Crimson. Retrieved 29 October 2012.
  4. ^ a b c d e f g h Drucker, Linda S.; Rabinovitz, Jonathan D. (12 March 1980). "Stephen Marglin". The Harvard Crimson. Retrieved 29 October 2012.
  5. ^ "Current and Former Junior Fellows: Listing by Term". Society of Fellows, Harvard University. Archived from the original on 2013-01-16. Retrieved 29 October 2012.
  6. ^ "Stephen A. Marglin: 1975 Fellow, Economics". gf.org. Archived from the original on 4 January 2013. Retrieved 26 October 2012.
  7. ^ Mansfield, Harvey; Cooper, Joseph; Rudolph, Susanne; Beer, Samuel (14 June 2007). "Arthur Maass: Faculty of Arts and Sciences—Memorial Minute". Harvard Gazette. Retrieved 9 November 2012.
    "Arthur Maass: 1954 Fellow, Political Science". John Simon Guggenheim Memorial Foundation. Archived from the original on 3 January 2013. Retrieved 9 November 2012.
  8. ^ "MacEwan Accepts One-Year Contract In Economics Dept". The Harvard Crimson. 14 March 1974. Retrieved 29 October 2012.
  9. ^ DeLong, Brad (20 June 2008). "Ask the Gemeinschaft: E. Roy Weintraub and Stephen Marglin Edition". Grasping Reality. Retrieved 30 August 2015.
  10. ^ "Stephen Marglin: Biography". harvard.edu. Retrieved 18 August 2012.
  11. ^ Willy Gianinazzi, André Gorz. Une vie, Paris, La Découverte, 2016, p. 160; Bryer 2002, p. 17.
  12. ^ Marglin, 1973, Marglin 1974.
  13. ^ Marglin 1975; Marglin 1979; Marglin 1984b; Chapter 7 in Marglin 1990b; Marglin 1991.
  14. ^ Marglin 2008, pp. 153–4.
  15. ^ Marglin, Stephen. "Why Is So Little Left Of The Left?". Z Papers (October–December 1992). Retrieved 29 October 2012.
  16. ^ Tunzelmann 2001, p. 10. "[The] debate, in regard to the First Industrial Revolution, [...] between Stephen Marglin and David Landes [was] over which was the more potent symbol of that revolution—the factory, interpreted as a governance mechanism, or the machinery? Landes' original survey (Landes 1969), drawn on his background in entrepreneurial history, had suggested a combination of technological and cultural factors explaining why Britain came first and why it later dropped behind. Marglin (1974), from a background in radical economics, instead took a strong labour-process view, in a paper entitled "What Do Bosses Do?" For him it was the control entrusted to the 'bosses' through the factory system that crucially defined that Industrial Revolution. Landes (1986) replied with a restatement more strongly favouring the technology as the sine qua non of early industrialisation. Both sides could accept some interdependence between governance changes and technological changes, but remained committed to their respective views about priority".
  17. ^ Landes 1986.
  18. ^ Interview with Marglin (2008). "Why Thinking Like an Economist Can Be Harmful to the Community". Challenge. 51 (2): 13–26. doi:10.2753/0577-5132510203. S2CID 154754425.
  19. ^ Marglin 2002, p. 48.
  20. ^ The Dismal Science, from the book's page on the Harvard University Press website.
  21. ^ White, Lawrence H. (10 March 2003). "Letter: Marglin Is Biased, Too". The Harvard Crimson. Retrieved 15 November 2012.
  22. ^ Shea, Christopher (14 December 2011). "The Econ-Alternative at Harvard". WSJ.com. Retrieved 29 October 2012.
  23. ^ Concerned students of Economics 10 (2 November 2011). "An Open Letter to Greg Mankiw". harvardpolitics.com. Retrieved 13 November 2013.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: numeric names: authors list (link)
  24. ^ "Stephen Marglin: Occupy Harvard, Economics and Ideology". The Institute Blog. Institute for New Economic Thinking. Archived from the original on 10 January 2012. Retrieved 10 December 2011.
  25. ^ Fiske, Courtney A. (7 November 2007). "Dershowitz, Gross and Marglin reflect on being 'Jewish in 2007'". The Harvard Crimson. Retrieved 29 October 2012.
  26. ^ "Economists Statement in Support of Occupy Wall Street". econ4.org. Retrieved 25 July 2013.
  27. ^ "Stephen Marglin: Interviews and Lectures: Occupy Harvard Teach-In on Heterodox Economics". harvard.edu. 7 December 2011. Archived from the original on 22 May 2013. Retrieved 29 October 2012. His Occupy lecture is available on YouTube.

Bibliography edit

External links edit