Tournament (graph theory)

Summary

In graph theory, a tournament is a directed graph with exactly one edge between each two vertices, in one of the two possible directions. Equivalently, a tournament is an orientation of an undirected complete graph. (However, as directed graphs, tournaments are not complete: complete directed graphs have two edges, in both directions, between each two vertices.[1]) The name tournament comes from interpreting the graph as the outcome of a round-robin tournament, a game where each player is paired against every other exactly once. In a tournament, the vertices represent the players, and the edges between players point from the winner to the loser.

Tournament
A tournament on 4 vertices
Vertices
Edges
Table of graphs and parameters

Many of the important properties of tournaments were investigated by H. G. Landau in 1953 to model dominance relations in flocks of chickens.[2] Tournaments are also heavily studied in voting theory, where they can represent partial information about voter preferences among multiple candidates, and are central to the definition of Condorcet methods.

If every player beats the same number of other players (indegree − outdegree = 0) the tournament is called regular.

Paths and cycles

edit
 
a is inserted between v2 and v3.

Any tournament on a finite number   of vertices contains a Hamiltonian path, i.e., directed path on all   vertices (Rédei 1934).

This is easily shown by induction on  : suppose that the statement holds for  , and consider any tournament   on   vertices. Choose a vertex   of   and consider a directed path   in  . There is some   such that  . (One possibility is to let   be maximal such that for every  . Alternatively, let   be minimal such that  .)   is a directed path as desired. This argument also gives an algorithm for finding the Hamiltonian path. More efficient algorithms, that require examining only   of the edges, are known. The Hamiltonian paths are in one-to-one correspondence with the minimal feedback arc sets of the tournament.[3] Rédei's theorem is the special case for complete graphs of the Gallai–Hasse–Roy–Vitaver theorem, relating the lengths of paths in orientations of graphs to the chromatic number of these graphs.[4]

Another basic result on tournaments is that every strongly connected tournament has a Hamiltonian cycle.[5] More strongly, every strongly connected tournament is vertex pancyclic: for each vertex  , and each   in the range from three to the number of vertices in the tournament, there is a cycle of length   containing  .[6] A tournament   is  -strongly connected if for every set   of   vertices of  ,   is strongly connected. If the tournament is 4‑strongly connected, then each pair of vertices can be connected with a Hamiltonian path.[7] For every set   of at most   arcs of a  -strongly connected tournament  , we have that   has a Hamiltonian cycle.[8] This result was extended by Bang-Jensen, Gutin & Yeo (1997).[9]

Transitivity

edit
 
A transitive tournament on 8 vertices.

A tournament in which   and       is called transitive. In other words, in a transitive tournament, the vertices may be (strictly) totally ordered by the edge relation, and the edge relation is the same as reachability.

Equivalent conditions

edit

The following statements are equivalent for a tournament   on   vertices:

  1.   is transitive.
  2.   is a strict total ordering.
  3.   is acyclic.
  4.   does not contain a cycle of length 3.
  5. The score sequence (set of outdegrees) of   is  .
  6.   has exactly one Hamiltonian path.

Ramsey theory

edit

Transitive tournaments play a role in Ramsey theory analogous to that of cliques in undirected graphs. In particular, every tournament on   vertices contains a transitive subtournament on   vertices. The proof is simple: choose any one vertex   to be part of this subtournament, and form the rest of the subtournament recursively on either the set of incoming neighbors of   or the set of outgoing neighbors of  , whichever is larger. For instance, every tournament on seven vertices contains a three-vertex transitive subtournament; the Paley tournament on seven vertices shows that this is the most that can be guaranteed.[10] However, Reid & Parker (1970) showed that this bound is not tight for some larger values of  .[11]

Erdős & Moser (1964) proved that there are tournaments on   vertices without a transitive subtournament of size   Their proof uses a counting argument: the number of ways that a  -element transitive tournament can occur as a subtournament of a larger tournament on   labeled vertices is   and when   is larger than  , this number is too small to allow for an occurrence of a transitive tournament within each of the   different tournaments on the same set of   labeled vertices.[10]

Paradoxical tournaments

edit

A player who wins all games would naturally be the tournament's winner. However, as the existence of non-transitive tournaments shows, there may not be such a player. A tournament for which every player loses at least one game is called a 1-paradoxical tournament. More generally, a tournament   is called  -paradoxical if for every  -element subset   of   there is a vertex   in   such that   for all  . By means of the probabilistic method, Paul Erdős showed that for any fixed value of  , if  , then almost every tournament on   is  -paradoxical.[12] On the other hand, an easy argument shows that any  -paradoxical tournament must have at least   players, which was improved to   by Esther and George Szekeres in 1965.[13] There is an explicit construction of  -paradoxical tournaments with   players by Graham and Spencer (1971) namely the Paley tournament.

Condensation

edit

The condensation of any tournament is itself a transitive tournament. Thus, even for tournaments that are not transitive, the strongly connected components of the tournament may be totally ordered.[14]

Score sequences and score sets

edit

The score sequence of a tournament is the nondecreasing sequence of outdegrees of the vertices of a tournament. The score set of a tournament is the set of integers that are the outdegrees of vertices in that tournament.

Landau's Theorem (1953) A nondecreasing sequence of integers   is a score sequence if and only if:[2]

  1.  
  2.  
  3.  

Let   be the number of different score sequences of size  . The sequence   (sequence A000571 in the OEIS) starts as:

1, 1, 1, 2, 4, 9, 22, 59, 167, 490, 1486, 4639, 14805, 48107, ...

Winston and Kleitman proved that for sufficiently large n:

 

where   Takács later showed, using some reasonable but unproven assumptions, that

 

where  [15]

Together these provide evidence that:

 

Here   signifies an asymptotically tight bound.

Yao showed that every nonempty set of nonnegative integers is the score set for some tournament.[16]

Majority relations

edit

In social choice theory, tournaments naturally arise as majority relations of preference profiles.[17] Let   be a finite set of alternatives, and consider a list   of linear orders over  . We interpret each order   as the preference ranking of a voter  . The (strict) majority relation   of   over   is then defined so that   if and only if a majority of the voters prefer   to  , that is  . If the number   of voters is odd, then the majority relation forms the dominance relation of a tournament on vertex set  .

By a lemma of McGarvey, every tournament on   vertices can be obtained as the majority relation of at most   voters.[18] Results by Stearns and Erdős & Moser later established that   voters are needed to induce every tournament on   vertices.[19]

Laslier (1997) studies in what sense a set of vertices can be called the set of "winners" of a tournament.[20] This revealed to be useful in Political Science to study, in formal models of political economy, what can be the outcome of a democratic process.[21]

See also

edit

Notes

edit
  1. ^ Weisstein, Eric W., "Tournament", MathWorld
  2. ^ a b Landau (1953).
  3. ^ Bar-Noy & Naor (1990).
  4. ^ Havet (2013).
  5. ^ Camion (1959).
  6. ^ Moon (1966), Theorem 1.
  7. ^ Thomassen (1980).
  8. ^ Fraisse & Thomassen (1987).
  9. ^ Bang-Jensen, Gutin & Yeo (1997).
  10. ^ a b Erdős & Moser (1964).
  11. ^ Reid & Parker (1970).
  12. ^ Erdős (1963)
  13. ^ Szekeres & Szekeres (1965).
  14. ^ Harary & Moser (1966), Corollary 5b.
  15. ^ Takács (1991).
  16. ^ Yao (1989).
  17. ^ Brandt, Brill & Harrenstein (2016).
  18. ^ McGarvey (1953); Brandt, Brill & Harrenstein (2016)
  19. ^ Stearns (1959); Erdős & Moser (1964)
  20. ^ Laslier (1997).
  21. ^ Austen-Smith & Banks (1999).

References

edit
  • Austen-Smith, D.; Banks, J. (1999), Positive Political theory, University of Michigan Press
  • Bang-Jensen, J.; Gutin, G.; Yeo, A. (1997), "Hamiltonian Cycles Avoiding Prescribed Arcs in Tournaments", Combinatorics, Probability and Computing, 6: 255–261
  • Bar-Noy, A.; Naor, J. (1990), "Sorting, Minimal Feedback Sets and Hamilton Paths in Tournaments", SIAM Journal on Discrete Mathematics, 3 (1): 7–20, doi:10.1137/0403002
  • Brandt, Felix; Brill, Markus; Harrenstein, Paul (2016), "Chapter 3: Tournament Solutions", in Brandt, Felix; Conitzer, Vincent; Endriss, Ulle; Lang, Jérôme; Procaccia, Ariel D. (eds.), Handbook of Computational Social Choice, Cambridge University Press, ISBN 9781107060432
  • Camion, Paul (1959), "Chemins et circuits hamiltoniens des graphes complets", Comptes Rendus de l'Académie des Sciences de Paris (in French), 249: 2151–2152
  • Erdős, P. (1963), "On a problem in graph theory" (PDF), The Mathematical Gazette, 47: 220–223, JSTOR 3613396, MR 0159319
  • Erdős, P.; Moser, L. (1964), "On the representation of directed graphs as unions of orderings" (PDF), Magyar Tud. Akad. Mat. Kutató Int. Közl., 9: 125–132, MR 0168494
  • Fraisse, P.; Thomassen, C. (1987), "A constructive solution to a tournament problem", Graphs and Combinatorics, 3: 239–250.
  • Graham, R. L.; Spencer, J. H. (1971), "A constructive solution to a tournament problem", Canadian Mathematical Bulletin, 14: 45–48, doi:10.4153/cmb-1971-007-1, MR 0292715.
  • Harary, Frank; Moser, Leo (1966), "The theory of round robin tournaments", American Mathematical Monthly, 73 (3): 231–246, doi:10.2307/2315334, JSTOR 2315334.
  • Havet, Frédéric (2013), "Section 3.1: Gallai–Roy Theorem and related results" (PDF), Orientations and colouring of graphs, Lecture notes for the summer school SGT 2013 in Oléron, France, pp. 15–19
  • Landau, H.G. (1953), "On dominance relations and the structure of animal societies. III. The condition for a score structure", Bulletin of Mathematical Biophysics, 15 (2): 143–148, doi:10.1007/BF02476378.
  • Laslier, J.-F. (1997), Tournament Solutions and Majority Voting, Springer
  • McGarvey, David C. (1953), "A Theorem on the Construction of Voting Paradoxes", Econometrica, 21 (4): 608–610, doi:10.2307/1907926, JSTOR 1907926
  • Moon, J. W. (1966), "On subtournaments of a tournament", Canadian Mathematical Bulletin, 9 (3): 297–301, doi:10.4153/CMB-1966-038-7.
  • Rédei, László (1934), "Ein kombinatorischer Satz", Acta Litteraria Szeged, 7: 39–43.
  • Reid, K.B.; Parker, E.T. (1970), "Disproof of a conjecture of Erdös and Moser", Journal of Combinatorial Theory, 9 (3): 225–238, doi:10.1016/S0021-9800(70)80061-8
  • Stearns, Richard (1959), "The Voting Problem", The American Mathematical Monthly, 66 (9): 761–763, doi:10.2307/2310461, JSTOR 2310461
  • Szekeres, E.; Szekeres, G. (1965), "On a problem of Schütte and Erdős", The Mathematical Gazette, 49: 290–293, doi:10.2307/3612854, MR 0186566.
  • Takács, Lajos (1991), "A Bernoulli Excursion and Its Various Applications", Advances in Applied Probability, 23 (3), Applied Probability Trust: 557–585, doi:10.2307/1427622, JSTOR 1427622.
  • Thomassen, Carsten (1980), "Hamiltonian-Connected Tournaments", Journal of Combinatorial Theory, Series B, 28 (2): 142–163, doi:10.1016/0095-8956(80)90061-1.
  • Yao, T.X. (1989), "On Reid conjecture of score sets for tournaments", Chinese Sci. Bull., 34: 804–808.

This article incorporates material from tournament on PlanetMath, which is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution/Share-Alike License.